General equilibrium tries to give an understanding of the whole economy using a bottom-up approach, starting with individual markets and agents. Macroeconomics, as developed by so-called Keynesian economists, uses a top-down approach where the analysis starts with larger aggregates. Since modern macroeconomics has emphasized microeconomic foundations, this distinction has been slightly blurred. However, many macroeconomic models simply have a 'goods market' and study its interaction with for instance the financial market. General equilibrium models typically model a multitude of different goods markets. Modern general equilibrium models are typically complex and require computers to help with numerical solutions.
Under capitalism, the prices and production of all goods are interrelated. A change in the price of one good, say bread, may affect another price, for example, the wages of bakers. If bakers differ in tastes from others, the demand for bread might be affected by a change in bakers' wages, with a consequent effect on the price of bread. Calculating the equilibrium price of just one good, in theory, requires an analysis that accounts for all of the millions of different goods that are available.
Table of contents |
2 Modern Concept of general equilibrium in economics 3 Unresolved problems in general equilibrium |
The first attempt in Neoclassical economics to model prices for a whole economy was made by Leon Walras. Walras' Elements of Pure Economics provides a succession of models, each taking into account more aspects of a real economy
(two commodities, many commodities, production, growth, money). Many think Walras was unsuccessful and the later models in this series inconsistent. Nevertheless, Walras first laid down a research program much followed by 20th century economists. In particular, Walras' agenda included the investigation of when equilibria are unique and stable.
Walras also first introduced a restriction into general equilibrium theory that some think has never been overcome, that of the tatonnement or groping process.
The tatonnement process is a tool for investigating stability of equilibria. Prices are cried, and agents register how much of each good they would like to
offer (supply) or purchase (demand). No transactions and no production
take place at disequilibrium prices. Instead, prices are lowered for goods
with positive prices and excess supply. Prices are raised for goods with
excess demand. The question for the mathematician is under what conditions
such a process will terminate in equilibrium in which demand equates to
supply for goods with positive prices and demand does not exceed supply for
goods with a price of zero. Walras was not able to provide a definitive
answer to this question.
In partial equilibrium analysis, the determination of the price of a good is simplified by just looking at the price of one good, and assuming that the prices of all other goods remain constant. The Marshallian theory of supply and demand is an example of partial equilibrium analysis. Partial equilibrium analysis is adequate when the first-order effects of a shift in, say, the demand curve do not shift the supply curve. Anglo-American economists became more interested in general equilibrium in the late 1920s and 1930s after Piero
Sraffa's demonstration that Marshallian economists cannot account for the
forces thought to account for the upward-slope of the supply curve for a
consumer good.
If an industry uses little of a factor of production, a small increase in
the output of that industry will not bid the price of that factor up. To
a first order approximation, firms in the industry will not experience
decreasing costs and the industry supply curves will not slope up. If
an uses an appreciable amount of that factor of production, an increase
in the output of that industry will exhibit increasing costs. But such
a factor is likely to be used in substitutes for the industry's product,
and an increased price of that factor will have effects on the supply
of those substitutes. Consequently, the first order effects of a shift
in the supply curve of the original industry under these assumptions
include a shift in the original industry's demand curve. General
equilibrium is designed to investigate such interactions between
markets.
Continential European economists made important advances in the 1930s.
Walras' proofs of the existence of general equilibrium often were
based on the counting of equations and variables. Such arguments are
inadequate for non-linear systems of equations and do not imply that
equilibrium prices and quantities cannot be negative, a meaningless
solution for his models. The replacement of certain equations by
inequalities and the use of more rigorous mathematics improved
general equilibrium modeling.
The modern conception of general equilibrium is provided by a
model developed jointly by Kenneth Arrow and Gerard Debreu
in the 1950s. Gerard Debreu presents this model in Theory of Value
(1959) as an axiomatic model, following the
style of mathematics promoted by Bourbaki. In such an approach,
the interpretation of the terms in the theory (e.g., goods, prices)
are not fixed by the axioms.
Three important theorems have been proved in this framework. First,
existence theorems show that equilibria exist under certain
abstract conditions. The first fundamental theorem of welfare states
that every market equilibrium is Pareto optimal under certain
conditions. The second fundamental theorem of welfare states that
every Pareto optimum is supported by a price system, again under
certain conditions. These conditions were stated in the language
of mathematical topology. The proofs used such concepts as
seperating hyperplanes and fixed point theorems.
Three important interpretations of the terms of the theory have
been often cited. First, supposed commodities are distinguished
by the location where they are delivered. Then the Arrow-Debreu
model is a spatial model of, for example, international trade.
Second, suppose commodities are distinguished by when they are
delivered. That is, suppose all markets equilibriate at some
initial instant of time. Agents in the model purchase and sell
contracts, where a contract specifies, for example, a good to
be delivered and the date at which it is to be delivered. The
Arrow-Debreu model of intertemporal equilibrium contains forward
markets for all goods at all dates. No markets exist at any future
dates.
Third, suppose contracts specify states of nature which affect
whether or not a commodity is to be delivered:
"A contract for the transfer of a commodity now specifies, in addition to
its physical properties, its location and its date, an event on the
occurrence of which the transfer is conditional. This new definition
of a commodity allows one to obtain a theory of [risk] free from any
probability concept..." (Debreu 1959)
These interpretations can be combined. So the complete Arrow-Debreu
model can be said to apply when goods are identified by when they
are to be delivered, where they are to be delivered, and under what
circumstances they are to be delivered, as well as their intrinsic
nature. So there would be a complete set of prices for contracts such as
"1 ton of Winter red wheat, delivered on 3rd of January in Minneapolis, if
there is a hurricane in Florida during December". A general equilibrium
model with complete markets of this sort seems to be a long way from
describing the workings of real economies.
Research building on the Arrow-Debreu model has revealed some problems with the
model. The Sonnenschein-Mantel-Debreu results show that, essentially, any
restrictions on the shape of excess demand functions are essentially
arbitrary. Some think this implies that the Arrow-Debreu model lacks
empirical content. At any rate, Arrow-Debreu equilibria cannot be
expected to be unique, stable, or determinate.
A model organized around the tatonnnement process has been said to be
a model of a centrally planned economy, not a decentralized market
economy. Some research has tried, not very successfully, to develop
general equibrium models with other processes. In particular, some
economists have developed models in which agents can trade at out-of-equilibrium prices and such trades can affect the equilibria to which the economy tends.
Particularly noteworthy are the Hahn process, the Edgeworth process,
and the Fisher process.
The Arrow-Debreu model of intertemporal equilibrium, in which forward
markets exist at the initial instant for goods to be delivered at each
future point in time, can be transformed into a model of sequences of
temporary equilibrium. Sequences of temporary equilibrium contain
spot markets at each point in time. Roy Radner found that in order
for equilibria to exist in such models, agents (e.g., firms and
consumers) must have unlimited computational capabilities.
Although the Arrow-Debreu model is set out in terms of some
arbitrary numeraire, the model does not encompass money. Frank Hahn,
for example, has investigated whether general equilibrium models
can be developed in which money enters in some essential way. The
(unsatisfied) goal is to find models in which whether or not
money exists alters equilibrium solutions, perhaps because the
initial position of agents depends on monetary prices, for example,
when they have debts.
Some critics of general equilibrium modeling contend that much
research in these models constitutes exercises in pure matheamtics
with no connection to actual economies.
"There are endeavors that now pass for the most desirable kind of
economic contributions although they are just plain mathematical
exercises, not only without any economic substance but also
without any mathematical value" (Nicholas Georgescu-Roegen 1979).
Georescu-Roegen cites as an example a paper that assumed more
traders than there are points on a real line.
Although modern models in general equilibrium theory demonstrate that under certain circumstances prices will indeed converge to equilibria, critics hold that the assumptions necessary for these results are completely unrealistic. The necessary assumptions include perfect rationality of individuals; complete information about all prices both now and in the future; and the conditions necessary for perfect competition.
Frank Hahn defends general equilibrium modeling on the grounds that it
provides a negative function. General equilibrium models show what the
economy would have to be like for an unregulated economy to be
Pareto efficient. Note that Hahn's defense drops any claim that
general equilibrium models describe actual capitalist economies.
Some economists reject equilibrium theory outright in favour of more pragmatic models based more closely on observation of the economy.
History of General Equilibrium Modeling
Modern Concept of general equilibrium in economics
Unresolved problems in general equilibrium
List of Marketing Topics | List of Management Topics |
List of Economics Topics | List of Accounting Topics |
List of Finance Topics | List of Economists |